STRIPES ON SALE

An American TV show backs commercial breeding of tigers. But farming the big cat, writes Jay Mazoomdaar, cannot save the species in the wild.

New Indian Express, 17 May, 2009

The cat is slowly coming out of the bag. For long, the world suspected tacit official patronage of illegal tiger farms in China even after Beijing was forced to ban trade in tiger parts in 1993. Then, before the last meeting of the Conve­ntion on International Trade in Endangered Species (CITES) in 2008, Chinese officials unsuccessfully argued how the ban had cost their economy $4 billion and that captive-bred tigers could sustain the trade and also replenish the wild stock.

The farming lobby claims that providing a low-priced supply of tiger parts to customers will reduce the profit margins of poachers, making killing of wild tigers unviable. So their solution for saving tigers from extinction is to breed them commercially in farms as we currently breed chicken or cattle. This concept has many takers in the US, the only country with a pet tiger population larger than China’s. But this lobby also needs some support in India, the country with more than half of the world’s remaining wild tigers, and the campaign is gaining momentum.

First it was Barun Mitra, head of Liberty Institute who “visited China as a guest of the government to learn about tiger conservation”. Then it was Jaithirth Rao, India’s leading banker-turned-entrepreneur-turned-columnist. And now it is John Stossel, America’s star consumer reporter who anchors the highly popular 20/20 show. Between them, they have occupied prime news space on some top media organisations — New York Times, India Today, The Indian Express, Hindustan Times and, of course, ABC News.

But for all that, sample this. To name only two reporters, Danny Penman (Daily Mail) and Simon Parry (PostMagazine) documented last year how the Xiongsen Park in Guilin, China, was farming tigers in hundreds — each squeezed in like a battery hen — so that they could be eaten or turned into wine.

While Penman mentioned 140 tigers in the freezer to be served up on a menu as strips of stir-fried tiger with ginger and vegetables or tiger soup or spicy red curry made with tender tiger strips, Parry recalls the park’s sales manager Xhao Runghui ruing how he could not advertise tiger wine in Beijing because the Olympics were coming up.

However gruesome the idea of consuming tiger meat or wine may sound, it is not the reason why tiger farming is a remarkably dumb idea. Ethics or values aside, tiger farming simply does not make any economic or ecological sense.

First, farming only makes poaching more rewarding. Anyone who has an idea of a tiger’s daily consumption would know how much it costs to rear a tiger in captivity before it becomes “marketable”. If it must bring a reasonable margin in the market, it cannot be low-priced. Wild tigers virtually come for free and mean “total profit” to poachers. So in an open market, a poacher’s incentives would actually be greater as there would be no way to distinguish the bones of ‘farmed’ tigers from those of wild tigers.

Second, the argument that tigers — like chicken or sheep — will never go extinct if we farm them for consumption is misleading. Conservation is not just about saving tigers from going extinct but saving the tigers in the wild. Otherwise, we already have enough tigers in the zoos to secure live specimens for many generations to come.

The challenge before us is to save the tiger in the wild, so that with the tiger flourishing at the top of the food chain, everything down the pyramid flourishes. If the pyramid is alive, so will be the forests around it and the water systems that are sustained by such forests.

The farming lobby often cites the example of crocodiles having become successful commercial animals with an estimated two million harvested each year in Australia, South Africa and the US. But crocodiles are found in 91 countries and there are 23 surviving species. For each tiger in the wild, there were always hundreds of crocodiles. However, commercial success cannot save an endangered species in the wild. The Chinese themselves could do precious little about their highly endangered alligators. Despite repeated attempts at captive breeding and release since 1979, to quote Xinhua, there are just about 150 Chinese alligators left in the wild.

And, finally, what about China’s own tiger experience? Their tiger farms have been trading legally for years (with implicit official support since 1993). Today, China has thousands of tigers in cages but less than 50 survive poaching in the wild.

Unfortunately, reintroduction of captive-bred or farmed tigers in the wild has never succeeded. No wonder even the Chinese plan to reintroduce tigers bred in a South African zoo in its forests is yet to take off.

So then, how do we save the tiger? Well, to borrow a phrase from the farming lobby, by generating strong incentives. But for that we need not domesticate and kill tigers. We have to integrate efficient protection and practical management plans with popular participation.

As a rule, we have to involve the locals — not only for menial jobs — but also in protection work and responsible tourism. Protected well, our wilderness will not only ensure our food and water security but also sustain a multi-billion dollar tourism industry. If alive in the wild, the tiger will remain the ultimate mascot of that economy.

The writer is an independent journalist and filmmaker. mazoomdaar@gmail.com

Governments change, a few policies don't

Whichever coalition is to share power for the next five years, mindless plunder of natural resources will continue unabated

NEW INDIAN EXPRESS, 15 May, 2009

PSEPHOLOGISTS and punters may burn their fingers trying to predict the results of this Lok Sabha election and the nature of the subsequent political realignments, but I’m not giving away any prizes for guessing the next government’s stand on certain issues. Whichever formation comes to power, the defence budget will go up. No government can significantly alter India’s foreign policy. No finance minister dare slash self-defeating subsidies. Corruption will stay institutionalised. And mindless plunder of our natural resources will continue.

I understand that the demands of development will always make a few sacrifices necessary. In an informed, responsible society, such decisions are made in the absence of an alternative. In India, successive governments have cleared projects that allow destruction of forest, riverine or marine ecosystems in amazing hurry and without any economic or scientific justification.

What helps this tradition of official plunder is a general atmosphere of mistrust that dismisses even the most logical voices as anti-development ranting. Every time activists and experts object to development projects, we reduce the case to a petty growth-versus-green debate. Surely, neither a blanket approval nor ban on such projects makes sense. But why cannot the authorities decide every case on its merit, relying on an objective cost-benefit analysis?

Take a highway project cutting through a sanctuary. To calculate the cost involved, the authorities need to formulate a standard mechanism for computing, in monetary terms, the value of the ecological loss in question. The benefit is easier to calculate: how much will be saved on construction expense by avoiding a longer alignment outside the forest and how much time and fuel will be saved by vehicles avoiding such a detour. Unless government agencies derive such concrete cost-benefit comparatives project by project, their decisions will continue to be arbitrary and leave room for manipulation.

Why only highways, most government approvals for destroying forests through mining or construction fail to justify the need for such drastic measures. Consider the infamous example of Kudremukh Iron Ore Company Limited which was ripping apart one of India’s best forests for opencast mining even though the quality of iron sludge there was so inferior that the same could be obtained from hundreds of other places in the country.

Take our dams. Still considered a great symbol of development, most dams are not only harmful, they are unnecessary. For example, Gujarat boasts nearly 400 water bodies, other than the rivers, and a total water surface of over 2,000 sq km. Still the state’s overdrive for irrigation has led to construction of more than 200 dams with a total inundation area of about 1,400 sq km. Apart from submerging hundreds of hectares of forest land under reservoirs, so many dams and their massive irrigation network are destroying river ecologies and fast turning large areas saline.

Unfortunately, our governments do not desist from quick-fix measures even when they bring disastrous consequences. Consider the tragedy of the Kosi, notorious for devastating floods in north Bihar. Embankments stopped the river’s natural dispersion of sediments on the floodplains, making the riverbed rise by 12-15 feet with silt. Modern hydrology says that a meandering river with heavy silt load, like Kosi that has drifted 160 km in the past 250 years, cannot be stifled to equilibrium. Such rivers need to be tackled with spatial flood protection measures, allowing room for moderate flooding. But even after thousands of lives have been lost, the government is again trying to build embankments on Kosi and, in the process, setting the stage for another flooding disaster.

Let alone forests and rivers, something as basic as water supply can lead governments to seek outlandish solutions where simple correction of the system will do. Delhi Jal Board (DJB) has revived the 15-year-old Renuka dam project in the name of meeting the Capital’s water shortage.

Ironically, Delhi wastes more than 40 per cent of its supplied water due to distribution losses, largely due to old, corroded pipelines. While the Renuka project earmarks 275 million gallon water per day for Delhi, DJB can save up to 268 million gallon per day by fixing the distribution network. This should not be a tough task if DJB diverts the Rs 3,000 crore allocated for construction of the Renuka dam to modernise its distribution and regulatory network.

Instead, the authorities have decided to inundate 2,000 hectares of forest and agricultural land in an eco-sensitive lower Himalayan landscape. The plan includes denotification and submergence of the Renuka Wildlife Sanctuary and displacement of at least 700 families. Moreover, no assessment has been done of the impact of the proposed dam on the nearby Renuka Lake, a wetland that was declared a Ramsar site (under the International Ramsar Convention) in 2005. But of course, it is easier to dam a river than fix leaking pipelines or rein in rich Delhiites who still love to use garden hoses to wash their cars.

As long as this mindset determines policy making, I have little hope that the next government, whatever the unique arithmetic of the Lok Sabha, will do anything different to secure the country’s precarious ecological future. True, none of our politicians ever sought mandate on the environmental plank. But can we not expect a little common sense from our governments though it never figures on any list of poll promises?

(The writer is an independent journalist and filmmaker. E-mail: mazoomdaar@gmail.com)